----------1 Date: Thu, 1 Aug 2002 07:57:28 -0400 From: Albert Henderson <chessNIC@compuserve.com> Subject: Statement from Sage (Bad research) on Wed, 31 Jul 2002 Frieda Rosenberg <friedat@EMAIL.UNC.EDU> wrote: [snip] > Thanks, Dan, for getting the argument "back on track." I don't think > that splitting hairs about abstractions does anything for arguments > about research quality or library funding, but for what it's worth, you > raised questions of historical interest. The quoted Mr Price pegged the > modern form of the scientific article at "about a century" ago, after a > long period of resistance from scientists who felt that only monographs > could justly cover a subject. (New ways of doing things are always > resisted!) Price also noted the rise of collaborative research, which > compensated for scientists with "less than one paper" in them (his > words) and allowed "fractional scientists" to do research! Donald deB. > Beaver, a former collaborator of Price, offers this in his recent > article, "Reflections on scientific collaboration (and its study)" > (Scientometrics, 52:3(2001):365-77: "Teamwork, or giant collaborations, > represents a new paradigm for the organizational structure of > research." He describes how "giant teams" can now deploy great numbers > of students who can bring in a publishable amount of data in three > months in contrast to the five years previously required by a single > researcher with his own student help. If this isn't a change, I don't > know what is... Sorry I couldn't wait for ILL to produce your source. A similar article appeared in JASIST [610-614. 2001] Price's (Lotka's) law can indeed break down when you have articles authored by 100 or more researchers and you limit your data to physics institutes! When applied to the entire academic R&D universe, however, the effect is insignificant. The misnamed 'new paradigm' is an abberation. It appears only under the most extreme disturbances. When Price described 'big science' in 1963, he wrote, "if we know how many papers are published in a field, we can compute the number of men who have written them." [LITTLE SCIENCE BIG SCIENCE p. 63] I really don't think that anything has changed since then. Best wishes, Albert Henderson Former Editor, PUBLISHING RESEARCH QUARTERLY 1994-2000 <70244.1532@compuserve.com> ----------2 Date: Thu, 1 Aug 2002 07:57:29 -0400 From: Albert Henderson <chessNIC@compuserve.com> Subject: Re: Statement from Sage (Bad research) on Tue, 30 Jul 2002 Peter Picerno <ppicerno@NOVA.EDU> wrote: [snip] > The argument "Referees are not provided with libraries that are > comprehensive enough that they can actually check unfamiliar sources and > verify the claims on which a particular piece of research is based ..." > particularly caught my attention because it makes no sense at all in these > days of lightening-swift ILL and document delivery (not to mention > e-publishing). If a referee doesn't know about ILL and Document Delivery, > then one wonders if they should be refereeing another author's work at all. The most recent studies indicate that neither authors nor referees bother to check sources. For example, a number of top medical journals ask their authors to interpret data "in light of the totality of the available evidence." They don't, of course. Moreover, the referees let the authors get away with it. [J A M A 276:637-639. 1996] That observation barely hints at the cost of poor preparation. Last year, a Johns Hopkins volunteer died. Of the inquiry that followed, the Chronicle of Higher Education wrote, "In particular, the office noted that researchers had "failed to obtain published literature about the known association between hexamethonium and lung toxicity" and that the substance was not currently approved by the U.S. Food and Drug Administration for use in humans." [47(47):A25. 2001]. Some medical librarians have noted this information could be located on Google! Why isn't a medical librarian part of the research team that prepared and reviewed the proposal?! My impression was that the author probably relied on one of the johnny-come-lately databases (that covers only the last few years) and the reviewers rubber-stamped the proposal. In short, having a great collection and all the latest techno-gizmos is no good if authors and referees don't use them. A 1994 General Accounting Office study of peer review as applied to grant proposals indicated, "Although most reviewers reported expertise in the general areas of the proposals they reviewed, many were not expert on closely related questions and could cite only a few, if any, references. This lack of proximate expertise was most pronounced at NIH. However, although this raises questions about the relative adequacy of NIH reviews and ratings, the greater proximity of NSF reviewers makes them potentially more vulnerable to apparent or actual self-interest in their reviews." GAO/PEMD-94-1. Of course the greatest conflict of interest is to be found in the management of institutions that prepare the proposals. They have the most to lose from a peer review bottleneck of detailed criticism that would send proposals back to the drawing board. It is to the benefit of institutional cash flow if authors and referees break the rules like so many Nancy Drews. I doubt that a few technological innovations will change human nature. What is needed is a financial reform of research preparation to provide (a) referees with more time to prepare critical reviews, (b) richer information resources, and (c) better management of authorship and peer review to engage specialists when appropriate. > Besides, the quoted statment implies that the purpose of libraries is to > acquire 'unafamiliar sources' so that the occasional referee can wander in > and check a reference. I will make it clear: The purpose of libraries is to support learning. A major purpose of peer review is to educate the referees. To these ends, it would make sense if every referee's library made it possible to check all authors' sources and if review management made checking sources mandatory. > If that, indeed, is their purpose, I'm afraid that > university administrations would be quite justified in slashing budgets and > personnel. Rather than being a morgue for little-used and little-demanded > information, most academic libraries strive to be a lively place where the > majority of its users information needs are met. Unfortunately, when their information needs are not met, users write off the library as a resource [as Michael K Buckland observed in BOOK AVAILABILITY AND THE LIBRARY USER. Pergamon 1975]. The lively 'Starbucks' approach may address some social needs, but advanced study requires rich collections and convenient hours. Best wishes, Albert Henderson Former Editor, PUBLISHING RESEARCH QUARTERLY 1994-2000 <70244.1532@compuserve.com> ----------3 Date: Thu, 1 Aug 2002 07:57:27 -0400 From: Albert Henderson <chessNIC@compuserve.com> Subject: Re: Statement from Sage (Bad research) on Wed, 31 Jul 2002 Dan Lester <dan@riverofdata.com> wrote: [snip] > As soon as you have a magic answer on how to get increased R&D funding > into the library, be sure to let us know. You could sell libraries > the secret and retire a wealthy man. It certainly isn't for lack of > trying by librarians that most of us have been unsuccessful in getting > significant chunks of the R&D dollars for the library. Looking for a magic idea? Herbert S White had one. In his White Papers column, he observed that in the competition for budget dollars, the failures of a library are more important than markers of satisfaction. (For some reason, librarians would rather emphasize the latter.) Crime statistics, for example, measure the inadequacy of law and order. The FBI's annual publicity makes headlines and propels police chiefs' annual budget requests through the approval process. Perhaps failures of library collections could support libraries' budget requests. [LJ 120,1 (Jan., 1995): 58, 60.] In other words, librarians and libraries would fare better by emphasizing the numbers of information requests that could _not_ be satisfied. I have offered a 'Collection Failure Quotient' -- the ratio of interlibrary borrowing and collection size [access v. ownership] -- for this purpose. [Journal of Academic Librarianship. 26,3:159-170. 2000.] There are other approaches to measure dissatisfaction including interlibrary borrowing failures, patron interviews, etc. Harold Varmus complained to Congress that many researchers used grant money to subscribe to journals [which should be available in the library]. A census of private subscriptions would be an interesting indicator of dissatisfaction. Speaking mainly about the expensive science serials that support sponsored R&D, another magic answer should lie in research overhead. Overhead accounts for 1/3 of $30 billion federally sponsored academic research spending (2000). Libraries are designated as an overhead factor. How much of the $10 billion overhead reimbursements supports libraries? It shouldn't be too hard to identify the costs associated with those expensive science journals. The definition of overhead expenses to be covered by reimbursements was originally agreed as "full accountable costs." If library overhead were handled in ways that actually reflected the ways that libraries are used by the researchers who prepare, review, and execute sponsored research, I believe library funding would be better. Unfortunately, library reimbursements are negotiated by financial managers, not by librarians. As a result, library reimbursements to go administrative slush funds, not to libraries. Worse, the money can be lost due to bureaucratic incompetence. The Inspector General of the National Science Board found examples costs that the General Accounting Office identified as unallowable or questionable. One example given was $7 million in library costs claimed by Stanford because the university "did not use the default method specified by OMB Circular A-21." [Federally Sponsored Research: How Indirect Costs are Charged by Educational and Other Research Institutions.] > AH> The SERIALS PRICES PROJECT REPORT of the Association > AH> of Research Libraries (1989) made 'excessive publication' > AH> a leading factor in its propaganda campaign of the early > AH> 1990s. The theme was amplified by SCIENCE, THE SCIENTIST, > AH> 60 MINUTES, and THE NEW YORK TIMES, whose editors never > AH> bothered to check the reliability of the ARL as a > AH> objective source. > > As always, one man's "objective source" is another man's "biased > source". We all have our own agendas, and we're certainly familiar > with yours. I believe, Mr. Henderson, that we'd all be able to work > together for a common goal if you weren't so busy biting the hand that > feeds you. I don't know of a single librarian that doesn't feel the > need for more funding for materials of all types, and the staff to > support their acquisition, storage, and access. I also don't know of > a single librarian that doesn't regularly make pleas to the university > administration for greater funding and the reasons therefor. First, I am not biting the hand that feeds me. I have campaigned for better library funding for quite a long time now. What puzzles me is the number of contra librarians. To address your point, can you can tell me the official position on library overhead of the Association of Research Libraries, the ACRL, or the American Library Association? Moreover, can you tell me why the ACRL standards for college and university libraries no long offer anything in the way of objective measures by which to gauge whether a library is acceptable or not. > Just because librarians are taking advantage of new technologies to > obtain materials that researchers (and others) request doesn't mean > that if it were "the old world" instead of "the new world" we wouldn't > love to have more shelves filled with these items. > > AH> The same sort of peer review that serves editors > AH> supports approvals of academic research grants now > AH> in the tens of billions of dollars with huge > AH> overhead allowances going to profitability. > > AH> It is pitiful. > > I know you're really convinced of this "profitability" in academia. > Profitability in the business world can produce fortunes for top > executives and profits for shareholders, as well as income for the > employees. > I credit Thorsten Veblen with identifying the problem. He pointed out that the university "is a corporation with large funds, and for men biased by their workaday training in business affairs it comes as a matter of course to rate the university in terms of investment and turnover." [The Higher Learning in America. 1918; reprint 1993 p. 62] Similar observations were set out by Robert Nisbet and Edward Shils. I have gone to financial statements and statistics for evidence (easily found). Clearly knowledge has lost priority to money. > If that profitability were present in academia, the same should hold > true for the university. Those of us who are employees get income for > doing our job. There are no shareholders as such. The top university > administrators certainly make six figure salaries, but I've not read > of any of them being taken away in handcuffs because they've diverted > funds to their million dollar mansions, bought any private jets, or > had interest free loans of tens of millions of dollars. See my article in SCHOLARLY PUBLISHING [Wiley 2002. p 8] for profit and spending trends 1970-1995. > AH> I have made a point of the ratio of > AH> interlibrary borrowing to total numbers of volumes, > AH> something that I call COLLECTION FAILURE QUOTIENT, > AH> but very little about acquisitions spending. > > That number will continue to increase as the amount of publishing > increases, and as the prices of those publication continue to increase > faster than almost any other component of the economy. Publishing activity increases with the growth of spending on academic R&D. Why doesn't library spending keep up? Are libraries part of research, or not?! Albert Henderson Former Editor, PUBLISHING RESEARCH QUARTERLY 1994-2000 <70244.1532@compuserve.com>